Fortunes on Both Sides?

The slave trade that linked Africa, Europe, and the Americas brought a gruesome torture, death as well as profit. As the slave trade boomed in the middle of the 18th century, some European intellectuals saw it as a model of free enterprise and of liberty. They were not slave traders or slaveship captains but very influential economic thinkers. They were a pioneering group committed to the principle of laissezfaire ― a term they themselves coined. Vincent de Gournay then a prominent figure, and was one of the first European intellectuals to argue for limitations on government intervention in the economy. Gournay and his companions organised campaigns for the deregulation of domestic and international trade, and they made the slave trade a key piece of evidence in their arguments.

Scholars demonstrate that the Industrial Revolution, centred on the mass production of cotton textiles in the factories of England and New England, depended on raw cotton grown by slaves on plantations in South America. Capitalists often confirmed the superiority of the industrial economies and their supposedly free labour. Free labour means the system in which workers are not enslaved but free to contract with any manufacturer they chose, free to sell their labour; and therefore, there is a labour market, not a slave market.

Since free labour was working with and dependent on raw materials produced by slaves, however, the simple distinction between an industrial economy of free labour on the one hand and a slave-based plantation system on the other falls apart. So too does the boundary between the southern ‘slave states’ and northern ‘free states’ in America. While the South grew rich from plantation agriculture that depended on slave labour, New England also grew rich off the slave trade, investing in the shipping and maritime insurance that made the transport of slaves from Africa to the America possible and profitable. The sale of enslaved Africans brought together agriculture and industry, north and south, forming a global commercial network from which the modern world emerged.

It is only in the past few decades that scholars have come to grips with how slavery and capitalism intertwined. But for the 18th-century French intellectuals who laid the foundations of laissez-faire capitalism, it made perfect sense to associate the slave trade with free enterprise. Their writings were aimed to convince the French monarchy to deregulate key businesses such as the sale of grain and trade with Asia. Only a few specialists read them today. Yet these pamphlets, letters and manuscripts clearly proclaim a powerful message: the birth of modern capitalism depended not only on the labour of enslaved people and the profits of the slave trade, but also on the example of slavery as a deregulated global enterprise.

For centuries after European colonisation of the Americas began, European governments regulated the Atlantic slave trade. They organised it in accordance with what was known as mercantilism. This was the authoritative economic thinking of the 16th, 17th and much of the 18th century. It favoured heavy government intervention, particularly in international trade. For mercantilist thinkers, trade was a kind of war in which nations could defeat their rivals by accumulating silver and gold, and by exporting manufactured goods while importing agricultural products. All aspects of trade were to be precisely organised in order to serve these goals, leaving little initiative to private traders. A few decades after Christopher Columbus’s arrival in the Caribbean in 1492, the Spanish monarchy thought that enslaving indigenous peoples of the Americas was not enough to supply its growing colonies’ need for labour. They then decided to turn to the slave trade in West Africa. Europeans and Arabs had long engaged in the African slave trade. Bartolomé de las Casas ― one of the Spanish critics of the horrific mistreatment of indigenous peoples ― supported this decision: Africans were better fit for hard labour than American Indians.

In a system known as the asiento (contract), the Spanish government began granting some European merchants special monopoly contracts. These allowed the traders to become the sole merchants permitted to sell slaves in a particular area. The Spanish government carefully controlled the whole economy of its American colonies, only allowing a select handful of foreigners to trade with its valuable possessions. Since the slave trade was one of the most lucrative sectors of colonial commerce, it was particularly restricted. In the 16th century, the Spanish government granted these asiento monopolies over the slave trade in its colonies to Italian, German and Portuguese investors who came from countries in the orbit of Spain’s global empire. However, by the end of the 17th century, Spain was declining as a military power. It was less and less able to grant the asiento to merchants of its own choosing. Other European empires desired the asiento for themselves, and tried to seize it. In 1701, the Spanish king died with no heir. The French king, Louis XIV, invaded Spain and installed his own grandson on the throne. One of the newly crowned ruler’s first acts was to hand over control of the asiento to his grandfather. Now France would have the sole right to supply Spain’s colonies with enslaved Africans, ensuring huge profits for French slave traders.

The asiento was a rich prize, and France was not the only country to desired it. Louis XIV’s enemies quickly snatched it back from him. Other European countries such as England and Holland formed an alliance against France, initiating the War of the Spanish Succession (1701-1714). This ended in French defeat. As part of its share of the spoils of war, England took control of the asiento. In order to run this valuable new commerce, it created an innovative corporation called the South Sea Company. This was one of the first joint stock companies to attract thousands of investors, who imagined that the profits of the slave trade to the Spanish colonies made it a sure bet. The price of shares spiralled ever higher, until the frenzy of speculation triggered a nationwide financial crisis. Shocked by the sudden rise and disastrous fall of the value of their shares, bewildered investors discovered the stock-market ‘bubble’, the first of its kind ― more slaves in the colonies meant more consumption of sugar, coffee and chocolate in Europe: feeding on itself, the slave trade seemed to expand without limits.

While the English public was trading shares in the slave trade, French slave traders faced an uncertain future. The end of the War of the Spanish Succession deprived them of access to what had been their best markets. They demanded action from the government but the French government had financial problems of its own. The war left it burdened with massive debts and desperate for a way out.

Due to the these economic crises, the French government took a desperate step. In defiance of mercantilist ideas, it deregulated the slave trade. For the first time, the monarchy allowed private firms to send slave ships to Africa and on to the Americas. There would be no new state monopoly company to control the French slave trade. From a business angle, the result was a huge success. Private traders sent increasing numbers of slaves to France’s colonies of Martinique, Guadeloupe and Saint-Domingue (now Haiti). At the beginning of the 18th century, a few thousand slaves were brought to the French Caribbean each year. More than a 100,000 slaves were taken there annually by the end of the 18th century. The huge increase in the volume of slaves coming to France’s colonies transformed these islands into centres of global commerce. The more that traders sent slaves to the colonies, the more colonial plantation owners could expand their production of sugar. The cheaper sugar became, the more a growing number of Europeans could consume it, often paired with other colonial substances such as coffee and chocolate. These were also produced in tropical colonies by enslaved Africans. More slaves in the colonies meant more consumption of sugar, coffee and chocolate in Europe, and thus also meant even more demand for slaves. Feeding on itself, the slave trade seemed to expand without limits.

Slavery was barbaric everywhere in the Americas, but slavery in France’s sugar plantations might have been the most barbaric ones. Many enslaved Africans died before reaching the Caribbean colonies and, once they arrived, their average life expectancy was less than five years. They were simply worked to death. It was no accident that Saint-Domingue (the largest French colony) would be the scene of the most violent and vital slave revolt in the history of the Americas: this revolt forced the French government to abolish slavery in 1793; it broke out in the midst of the French Revolution. When France began to attempt to restore slavery 10 years later, a new revolt broke out. This time, the rebels won their independence from France, creating the Republic of Haiti in 1804.

While tensions brewed in Saint-Domingue, the barbaric of the Atlantic slave trade slowly began to register on French consciences. In the 1780s, on the eve of the French Revolution, anti-slavery activists gathered in Paris to lobby for the abolition of the slave trade. (A generation before this, another group of activists known as the Gournay Circle were more concerned about the lessons that the growing slave trade had for the French economy.) They were inspired by Vincent de Gournay, the intellectual who coined the phrase laissez-faire, laissez-passer (let do, let go) to sum up his innovative views.

Gournay and his circle revolutionised economic thinking by calling for the systematic elimination of international and domestic trade barriers such as state monopolies, guilds and prohibitions on foreign imports. Never before had a group of thinkers so directly challenged mercantilist ideas. When the French monarchy had deregulated the slave trade in the 1720s, it had acted out of desperation in regard to a particular crisis, not out of a conviction that mercantilism itself had failed. It was only three decades later that members of the Gournay Circle observed the dramatic growth of the slave trade and slave-based colonial economies, and drew a more general conclusion. They argued that the slave trade’s success proved that deregulation should be pursued not just as a last-ditch tactic, but as a deliberate and comprehensive strategy. The slave trade showed that the top-down regulations of mercantilism were outdated.

The Gournay Circle lobbied the French monarchy for sweeping changes, and one of its most important targets was the French East India Company. Deprived of its monopoly over the French Atlantic slave trade in 1720, this state monopoly company was now responsible for all French trade with the Indian Ocean region. No private traders were allowed to sail east past the Cape of Good Hope. The Company managed to make a reasonable profit most years. However, it neither satisfied French demand for South Asian commodities nor exported more than a handful of French goods to South Asia. It ran a massive trade deficit and by the middle of the 18th century was sinking into debt.

Sensing an opportunity to advance their ideals of laissez-faire, the Gournay Circle attacked the Company by comparing the unsatisfactory state of France’s trade with the Indian Ocean to the flourishing and ever-expanding Atlantic slave trade. The first revealed the weaknesses of mercantilism, and the second showed the strengths of laissez-faire. He first developed this argument in a series of unpublished Observations on the Company written in the mid-1750s. He wrote, “The largest branches of commerce that the nation [France] has acquired since 1720… have been obtained only by parting from the Company’s privilege”. In the Atlantic market, where Law’s Company had lost the right the monopolise trade, business boomed. In the Asian market, where the Company’s successor still had a monopoly, trade deteriorated. He pointed to the growth of France’s Caribbean colonies after the deregulation of the slave trade. He stated, “The islands of Saint Domingue and Martinique would still be almost entirely without Negroes and thus without agriculture” if the monarchy had not deregulated the slave trade.

André Morellet, Gournay’s follower, continued the latter’s activism, and became the spokesman for a movement against the French East India Company. In 1769, he published On the Current Condition of the India Company (a pamphlet), which included Gournay’s notes in his own text, and expanded on their themes. He insisted that state enterprises in general should be abolished, and cited the success of French slave traders after 1720 as proof of the superiority of laissez-faire over mercantilism.

Morellet and his fellow free-traders’ campaign against the French East India Company, based on the example of the successfully deregulated Atlantic slave trade, was a triumph. They celebrated the deregulation of France’s trade with Asia in 1769. This victory, in turn, inspired economic intellectuals across Europe to consider how laissez-faire principles could be applied to other markets. His call for freedom of trade particularly struck Adam Smith, who referred to Morellet extensively in his The Wealth of Nations (1776) ― a milestone text that still informs many people’s belief in the free market.

Smith apparently became far more influential than Morellet. As his own version of laissez-faire ideas came to seem like common sense in the following century, the pioneering Gournay Circle was largely forgotten. Their sense that the slave trade was a prime example of free trade in action disappeared. Yet the writings of Gournay and Morellet reveal that modern capitalism is entangled with slavery in multiple and profound ways: slave labour supplied sugar, cotton, and other vital commodities. The profits from the sale of slaves brought fortunes on both sides of the continents, and in a disturbing paradox, the founding fathers of laissez-faire saw the slave trade as a showcase of liberty.

Leave a comment